Mancur Olson
USIFNO | 2013-06-25 14:06

 

Mancur Lloyd Olson, Jr. (ˈmænsər[1] or ˈmæŋkər; January 22, 1932 – February 19, 1998) was a leading American economist and social scientist. From 1967 until his death in 1998 Olson was a Professor of Economics at the University of Maryland, College Park. Among other areas, he made contributions to institutional economics on the role of private property, taxation, public goods, collective action and contract rights in economic development. Olson focused on the logical basis of interest group membership and participation. The reigning political theories of his day granted groups an almost primordial status. Some appealed to a natural human instinct for herding, others ascribed the formation of groups that are rooted in kinship to the process of modernization. Olson offered a radically different account of the logical basis of organized collective action.
 
In his first book, The Logic of Collective Action Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (1965), he theorized that “only a separate and ‘selective’ incentive will stimulate a rational individual in a latent group to act in a group-oriented way”; that is, members of a large group will not act in the group's common interest unless motivated by personal gains (economic, social, etc.). He specifically distinguishes between large and small groups, the latter of which can act simply on a shared objective. Large groups, however, will not form or work towards a shared objective unless individual members are sufficiently motivated.[2]
In 1982, he expanded the scope of his earlier work in an attempt to explain The Rise and Decline of Nations. The idea is that small distributional coalitions tend to form over time in countries. Groups like cotton-farmers, steel-producers, and labor unions will have the incentives to form lobby groups and influence policies in their favor. These policies will tend to be protectionist and anti-technology, and will therefore hurt economic growth; but since the benefits of these policies are selective incentives concentrated amongst the few coalitions members, while the costs are diffused throughout the whole population, the Logic dictates that there will be little public resistance to them. Hence as time goes on, and these distributional coalitions accumulate in greater and greater numbers, the nation burdened by them will fall into economic decline. Olson's idea is cited as an influence behind the Calmfors-Driffill hypothesis of collective bargaining.[3]
In his final book, Power and Prosperity, Olson distinguished between the economic effects of different types of government, in particular, tyranny, anarchy and democracy. Olson argued that a roving bandit (under anarchy) has an incentive only to steal and destroy, whilst a stationary bandit (a tyrant) has an incentive to encourage a degree of economic success, since he will expect to be in power long enough to take a share of it. The stationary bandit thereby takes on the primordial function of government - protection of his citizens and property against roving bandits. Olson saw in the move from roving bandits to stationary bandits the seeds of civilization, paving the way for democracy, which improves incentives for good government by more closely aligning it with the wishes of the population.[4]
To honor Olson's many contributions to the fields of Economics and Political Science, the American Political Science Association introduced the Olson Award to the best PhD dissertation in Political Economy.[5] In 2013 the University of Maryland announced the creation of a new endowed professorship The Mancur Olson Professor of Economics. [6]Maryland Professor of Economics Peter Murrell was appointed as the first Mancur Olson Professor.

See also 
John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy (1871) Book V, ch IX §12

Selected works 
The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force, (with Martin C. McGuire) in The Journal of Economic Literature, 1996, 34(1), pp. 72
 
美闻网---美国生活资讯门户
©2012-2014 Bywoon | Bywoon